The other side of student debt: Salaries of some private college presidents according to the Chronicle of Higher Education (source). These numbers are deceptive. According to the Huffington Post, the president of the University of Chicago, for example, was paid $3.3 million in 2011 if you include deferred compensation.
The other side of student debt: Salaries of presidents of some public (taxpayer-funded) colleges and universities according to the Chronicle of Higher Education (source), These numbers do not appear to include deferred compensation.
by Gaius Publius
This is the second part in a short series, "Killing a Parasite — Canceling Student Debt."
In Part 1, we made the case that the institutionalized and growing student debt crisis is not fed by predatory activity on creditors, but by parasitic activity. Predators kill, eat, and move on. Parasites disable, then live off the energy system of the disabled host for as long as they can keep the host alive. The argument there was simple: "Viruses are a form of parasite. So are credit card companies."
A non-human parasite: The "tongue-eating louse" is a parasitic crustacean of the family Cymothoidae. The parasite enters fish through the gills and then attaches itself to the fish's tongue, strangling and replacing it. Then it feeds on the fish as the fish feeds itself (source).
An especially pernicious form of "loan parasite" includes institutions preying financially on students, who incur their debt without current income to pay it, yet need a college degree to effectively compete in the post-graduation job market. Because at one point the federal government guaranteed many or most student loans in the U.S., private lenders eagerly extended credit to anyone who asked for it. No-risk lending is a no-brainer in the financial world.
These practices put a flood of money into the higher education system, money which continually drives up the price of higher education, even in public colleges and universities. Institutions charge what students can afford to pay, and since students were paying with government-backed loans — and today are paying with government-originated loans (see below) — they become a mere pass-through from lenders to college and university administrations.
Thus the more money this "program" makes available, the higher the tuitions charged by the receiving institutions. (It's really a racket in the classic sense, since students are coerced by the ever-increasing need for "credentialization" in an ever-deteriorating full-time labor market. Again, see below.)
A great deal of the new money that colleges and universities acquire ends up in the hands of the administrators themselves via growth in their number and growth in their salaries. At the top, many college presidents are paid like corporate CEOs, whom they consider themselves to resemble.
Paul Campos, writing in the New York Times, first identifies the "cover story," the comfortable myth, that's used to explain the booming cost of college (my emphasis throughout):
Once upon a time in America, baby boomers paid for college with the money they made from their summer jobs. Then, over the course of the next few decades, public funding for higher education was slashed. These radical cuts forced universities to raise tuition year after year, which in turn forced the millennial generation to take on crushing educational debt loads, and everyone lived unhappily ever after.He then shows that the truth is almost exactly opposite:
This is the story college administrators like to tell when they’re asked to explain why, over the past 35 years, college tuition at public universities has nearly quadrupled, to $9,139 in 2014 dollars. It is a fairy tale in the worst sense, in that it is not merely false, but rather almost the inverse of the truth.
In fact, public investment in higher education in America is vastly larger today, in inflation-adjusted dollars, than it was during the supposed golden age of public funding in the 1960s. Such spending has increased at a much faster rate than government spending in general. For example, the military’s budget is about 1.8 times higher today than it was in 1960, while legislative appropriations to higher education are more than 10 times higher.If car prices had gone up as fast as tuition over the same period, he writes, "the average new car would cost more than $80,000."
In other words, far from being caused by funding cuts, the astonishing rise in college tuition correlates closely with a huge increase in public subsidies for higher education.
Where is this money going? Among other places, into the pockets of the administrator class. Campos notes that "an analysis by a professor at California Polytechnic University, Pomona, found that, while the total number of full-time faculty members in the C.S.U. system grew from 11,614 to 12,019 between 1975 and 2008, the total number of administrators grew from 3,800 to 12,183 — a 221 percent increase."
To see the effect on the salaries of college presidents, the industry's CEO class, see the charts at the top.
Part 1 in this series looked at the Why question — Why should all student loans be canceled? — and answered it in economic terms, since ending student loan debt would benefit not just the students affected, but the economy as a whole. It also answered the Why question in moral terms: Ending the practice of parasitism, humans preying on humans, is a good thing in itself.
This piece looks at the How question — How should ending student loans be implemented? A future installment, the last, will address the What Next and What If We Don't questions. (Hint: Extreme parasitism is not a stable system, and the social consequences of extreme human suffering aren't limited to the ballot box.)
The Federal Government Is the Largest Originator of Student Loans
A little background before we get to the implementation. The largest originator and owner of student loans is now the U.S. government:
The Federal Student Aid (FSA) loan portfolio balances were $896 billion at the end of 2012. The FSA managed $473 billion under the Federal Direct Student Loan Program at the end of 2012. New loans originated under the program during 2012 totaled $106.7 billion. Loan portfolio balances managed by the FSA for the Federal Family Education Loan Program are slowly and steadily shrinking as new loans offered to students by the U.S. Department of Education originate under the FDSL program. Most of the growth in FDSL loan portfolio balances can be attributed to new loan originations, while being the sole government program for student loans. Another contributor to the rapid escalation in loan balances is due to the cost of higher education increasing rapidly, faster than inflation. Students are spending and borrowing more to finance their higher-priced, higher education.By comparison, note that the aggregate national student loan total, including both public and privately originated loans, is close to $1.5 trillion.
As of the 2015 GAO audit, the total of the Federal Student Aid loan portfolio was one trillion dollars. [Footnotes removed]
The percentage of private loans is actually much smaller that these numbers imply. According to a new paper by Scott Fullwiler, Stephanie Kelton, Catherine Ruetschlin, and Marshall Steinbaum, "The vast majority of [student] debt originates from federal lending, with the private student loan market accounting for just 7.6 percent ($99.7 million) of all student debt." (More from this paper below.)
Also note that the government-guaranteed loan program, in which private lenders were the source of the money, was eliminated only recently, in 2010:
Following the passage of the Health Care and Education Reconciliation Act of 2010, the Federal Direct Loan Program is the sole government-backed loan program in the United States. Guaranteed loans—loans originated and funded by private lenders but guaranteed by the government—were eliminated because of a perception that they benefited private student loan companies at the expense of taxpayers, but did not help reduce costs for students.So the loan guarantee program became a loan origination program. This makes the U.S. government today the major parasite driving the student loan crisis, though $100 million in private student debt is still a sizable prize for private lenders.
This also puts the U.S. government in a unique and powerful position — it can, if it wishes, solve this problem by its own action alone.
How to End the Student Loan Crisis
Part 1 of this series argued the benefits of a "debt jubilee" on all student loans in the U.S. The paper cited above also argues those benefits (see the Executive Summary). The mechanics of this cancellation, ways it can be implemented, are as follows. Note in the second bulleted paragraph how private loan debt would be handled (emphasis mine):
• The current portfolio of student loans held by the ED would be cancelled or, equivalently, borrowers would simply be allowed to stop making payments and any principal due on a given date would be cancelled at that time (that is, the loan would effectively be cancelled in stages as payments come due). As of the second quarter of 2016, the ED’s outstanding loans totaled $986.19 billion.Section II of the paper works out the effects of the various choices presented above. Note again that the effect on the national debt derives solely from the loan servicing amounts (interest payments), which are either lost to the government in the case of canceled government loans, or paid by the government in the case of privately issued loans. Canceling the outstanding loans balances themselves has no effect at all on the amount of federal debt.
• The federal government would either purchase and then cancel, or, equivalently, take over the payments on student debt currently held by the private sector. As with the ED’s loans, if the government purchases the privately held loans it can choose to cancel them immediately or as borrowers’ payments come due. The government-guaranteed loans are $266.69 billion, while nonguaranteed privately issued loans are $101.58 billion, both as of the second quarter of 2016. Having the government assume these payments or purchase and cancel the loans is preferable to cancellation by private investors. The latter would require the private sector to write down nearly $370 billion in both assets and equity, which could be highly destabilizing (or worse) for the affected sectors.
But Wouldn't This Disproportionately Benefit the Rich?
One of the chief objections to this proposal is that it's regressive, that it would disproportionately benefit the rich. The authors address this concern:
The Distributional Consequences of Student Debt, Student Debt Cancellation, and Debt-Free CollegeThis objection, overly simple and therefore easy to "sell," fails to take into account the wholesale changes that have occurred in both the student loan population and the U.S. labor market.
...[T]he main controversy over student debt generally and debt cancellation in particular has not been its macroeconomic impact, but rather the implications for people in different income and wealth quantiles and the impact on inequality. The controversy arises from the factual observation that among borrowers, those with the largest amount of debt outstanding tend to have the highest incomes, and those who spend the most on college (and who therefore—so the story goes—have the most to gain from the option of free college) come from the highest-earning families....
The widespread criticism of ambitious policies to address the student debt crisis, based on their supposedly regressive impact, is overdrawn. In some cases, it misinterprets the evidence about who is most burdened by student debt and who would benefit most from relief. In this section, we consider the evidence about the distribution of debt and debt burdens in the population and the evolution of those distributions over time. Our main point is that, while the largest loan balances are indeed held by comparatively high-earning households, the extent to which student debt is held by the rich has diminished significantly. Moreover, the argument that the distribution of the burden of student debt has not, in fact, changed very much, even as the total amount of debt outstanding has increased dramatically, fails to consider the significant changes in the population of people with any student debt at all. These issues of interpretation extend beyond accurately assessing the distributional impact of the policies we model—they point to larger problems with the assumptions behind existing higher education, student debt, and labor market policies. The student debt crisis is one of several linked manifestations of those problems. Others are wage stagnation, underemployment, and increasing inequality of household wealth.The bottom line is this: Student debt today is killing a generation in a way it didn't before. This is new and not a function of loans to students born of wealthy parents. It's a societal and generational problem, actually a multi-generational one, that hurts us all. The economic harm done to an entire generation of Americans is not captured by the objection that this is somehow a "regressive" proposal.
Student debt was once disproportionately associated with graduate school and with relatively well-off households, in part because it was possible to graduate from community college or a four-year public institution with little or no debt, and in even larger part because many people did not need to obtain any higher education credentials in order to access the labor market. What has happened in recent decades, and especially since the mid-2000s, is a vast expansion of student borrowing, such that the preponderant share of younger cohorts newly entering the labor market carry student debt. This expansion is due in part to much higher tuition, mostly thanks to state-level cutbacks in funding for higher education, and in part because it is simply far more difficult to access the labor market now without higher education credentials. And that “credentialization,” in turn, is due to the underperformance of the labor market since 2000 and especially since the financial crisis and the Great Recession that began in 2008. Since 2000, the most important federal labor market policy has been the extension of student debt and the encouragement of a larger share of the population to obtain debt-financed higher education credentials, on the theory that underemployment and stagnant wages were caused by a “skills gap” that could be remedied through debt-financed higher education. The most obvious and acute effect of that policy was the growth of the high-priced for-profit higher education sector, but it was also evident in rising enrollment across all types of institutions, even as tuition rose. The “skills gap” was a false diagnosis of the labor market’s problems, and hence the prescription of more debt-financed credentials not only failed to solve the problem, it also created its own problem in the form of unsustainable debt.
As the authors note, there's more in that section of the paper in support of these claims.
The Need for Debt-Free Public Higher Education
It's clear that this proposal, in my view necessary, must also be accompanied by the Sanders campaign proposal of debt-free public colleges and universities. The arguments for Sanders' proposal, on its own merits, were well explored during the campaign.
A major objection to Sanders' idea was again that it would mainly benefit the rich — an argument that ignores, disingenuously I think, the fact that the very wealthy do not send their children to public colleges and universities. Harvard University would not become tuition-free under Sanders' proposal.
But in the context of the current proposal for cancellation of all student debt, there's another reason for instituting debt-free public colleges and universities: moral hazard. Briefly, canceling debt without removing the reasons debt is incurred in the first place encourages reckless borrowing in the expectation of future cancellation.
The authors address the problem this way:
The primary theoretical criticism of debt cancellation plans focuses on the reaccumulation of debt following the cancellation, in particular the potential for problems of moral hazard to arise. From this perspective, debt relief today could change the incentives of future student debtors who may increase borrowing with the expectation that the loans will be forgiven, causing an even faster accumulation of debt and increasing the negative consequences at the household, local, and macroeconomic levels. The perverse incentives for unsustainable borrowing in this scenario are the result of inappropriate policy institutions that absolve borrowers of their debts while perpetuating the necessity of increasing debt. In order to avoid problems of moral hazard, any restructuring of student debt—including our debt cancellation proposal—should be accompanied by strong and appropriate policies that enforce the consequences of borrowing and address the market failures that lead to undesirable social costs. In combination with debt cancellation, publicly funded free or debt-free college would provide the institutional reform.In combination with a program like the one Sanders proposed during the campaign — free public colleges and universities — student debt cancellation would indeed and effectively address the current student debt crisis. The two proposals are a necessary pair and should be implemented together.
Finally, the "Fairness" Question
Which brings us to the last of the objections. In effect, it comes down to this: "I paid for my college degree with my hard work and sacrifice. I paid off all my loans, and believe me it was tough. But I did it. So why should others get a break that I didn't get?"
The problem here is what one writer described as "status quo bias," an emotional preference in which the "current baseline (or status quo) is taken as a reference point, and any change from that baseline is perceived as a loss."
but there's another bias as well, which could be called "retributional bias." This situation is similar to any in which an originally beneficial policy was first rescinded and then reinstated. Public education was largely free prior to the Reagan era, and with the GI Bill, millions paid next to nothing to attend. As the paper's authors point out, the largest loan balances were associated with post-graduate work.
But higher education policies changed under and after Reagan, reaching crisis proportions today. Should people trapped in debt by the blatant injustices of the post-Reagan world be allowed to veto, in the name of "fairness," the repeal of those injustices?
The essence of this objection is, "It's not fair that I was born at the wrong time." This has been described as being "trapped by history." Is it unfair that many be so trapped? Of course it is. But the perp in that unfairness is not the next generation to also be shackled, but the times themselves, the politicians who ruled them, and voters who kept them in power.
To therefore perpetuate that unfairness — to make, in effect, this generation suffer "because I had to" — is more than just unfair to them. It's cruel.
GP
With a Republican Party attempting to drag the nation back to 1870, and "democratic" Party doing absolutely nothing about it, why does America need education anyway? The 1% will just hire smart foreigners on H-1B visas and send them home once the ob is completed. The only job for real Americans will be to act as police to keep the rest of us in line. /s
ReplyDelete11:59, the democraps are part and parcel with America's "profitization of everything" meme. They support whatever gives them donations. profitized ed of all levels, prisons, war... you name it, they love the money they get from it.
ReplyDeleteWalk all this back in a straight line to Reagan, or more accurately, Reagan's handlers. Since Reagan, the world has been slowly reorganized, at the behest of the americans, along the lines of profitizing everything, but especially the commons.
Very soon... SSI, Medicare, the VA and other "socialized" commons will be converted to for-profit "services".
The owner class should be renamed and considered the vampire class. Props to Taibbi's "vampire squid" imagery.
But we have to acknowledge that we voters are laying down and baring our necks to the vampire caste while we should be staking and beheading instead.
As unlikely (zero %) as cancelling student debt is in this shithole, it is pointless without discussing free education from here forward. I'm glad to see GP did mention this, if only in passing.
ReplyDeleteThe analysis is good, but the Rx is poorly thought out. The transition period getting from "here" to "there" is going to be fraught with issues and difficulties. How education is delivered also has to be considered, if administrative parasitism is to be curtailed.
ReplyDeleteAFAICS, the main route to credential creep was too much labor supply, or perhaps too litle paid work supply. That imbalance needs to be reduced, which in turn will reduce the need to use credential filters for employment, which in turn will reduce demand for some forms of post K-12 education.